Home > News > Why isn’t the U.S. ready for a pandemic? For politicians, investing in prevention doesn’t pay off.
291 views 7 min 0 Comment

Why isn’t the U.S. ready for a pandemic? For politicians, investing in prevention doesn’t pay off.

Disaster spending helps get you reelected. Preventing disaster doesn’t.

- March 12, 2020

The federal government has been criticized for bungling its plan to adequately prepare for the spread of the new coronavirus. For instance, the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention have been unable to roll out mass-scale testing needed to contain the virus and understand its spread. By contrast, South Korea has been able to test hundreds of thousands of people and to begin to curtail the increasing death rate.

Some observers are blaming the lack of investment in public health infrastructure including the limited number of hospital beds, masks and medical devices. Further, the global health security team within the National Security Council was disbanded in 2018. However, this isn’t just a result of the Trump administration’s decisions. According to the Trust for America’s Health, the country’s lack of investment in public health stretches far back in history.

So why is the United States so poorly equipped for a mass pandemic? Much of the answer plausibly lies in politicians’ incentives. Having the federal government prepare for crises may be incredibly good value for money. But politicians get few or no benefits from doing so, since voters don’t reward them for being ready. This is why.

Preventive spending is very effective

In 2009, Andrew Healy and I published a paper in the American Political Science Review analyzing how voters responded to federal spending on preparing for and responding to natural disasters such as hurricanes, tornadoes and earthquakes. We collected data on county-level presidential election results, disaster damage and spending.

We found spending money on prevention is highly effective at mitigating future disasters. Benjamin Franklin famously said “an ounce of prevention is worth a pound of cure” — suggesting a 1-to-16 relationship between the costs of prevention and the costs of cure. That’s only a very slight exaggeration. We estimate that $1 spent on preparedness is worth about $15 in terms of the future damage it mitigates. We also looked at response spending, which usually comes in the form of checks sent to disaster victims. Unsurprisingly, that does not reduce future disaster damage.

Be careful what you’re learning from those coronavirus maps

But prevention doesn’t benefit politicians

Despite the clear efficiency of investing in preparation rather than response, prevention spending has decreased over the decades — while response spending has increased. Why has the federal government spent its money so poorly?

The answer lies in electoral incentives. We find that presidents who deliver relief spending after a disaster get a larger share of the votes in the next election. Specifically, if the incumbent party increases relief expenditures in a county from $1 per person (the 66th percentile for spending in the data) to $10 per person (the 93rd percentile in the data), the incumbent party will gain about 0.77 percentage points more in the next presidential vote. But there is a flat relationship between prevention spending in a county and presidential vote share — in other words, there’s no increase at all. This creates a clear incentive for government to not invest much in prevention, and instead to send help when disaster strikes.

Wuhan officials tried to cover up covid-19 — and sent it careening outward

Why do voters behave like this? Although we don’t have direct evidence, we offer numerous theories in the paper. For instance, voters may not be aware of preparation spending, or may not think it should affect their votes. Voters might also be shortsighted and discount the future. Perhaps voters prefer to receive individual benefits like checks in the mail rather than collective, shared public goods like prevention. Or maybe the problem lies in who gets the credit. Why would a politician spend money on preparation today if a future politician will reap the electoral rewards later on when a disaster occurs and the media celebrates those preparations?

This has consequences for covid-19

Of course, there’s always an electoral risk of a massive failure such as Hurricane Katrina or a viral pandemic. But often, politicians’ most attractive strategy will be to kick the can down the road. That’s true not just for singular disaster events, but also for systemic problems such as climate change and underfunded pensions.

3 ways the coronavirus could end Trump’s presidency

It is possible, at least in theory, that after horrific disasters, voters might start to reward politicians for investing in prevention. However, in the past, voters had notably short attention spans. Immediately after Hurricane Katrina in 2005, which devastated New Orleans, there were many proposals to shore up infrastructure and prepare for climate change. According to a survey conducted by the Kaiser Family Foundation, in late 2006, 30 percent of New Orleans residents said “repairing the levees, pumps, and flood walls” should be one of the top two priorities in the rebuilding efforts, ranking this item and crime control as their top two concerns. But once the event disappeared from the media cycle, the public’s desire for preparedness expenditure dissipated. The Kaiser Family Foundation surveyed New Orleans residents again in 2008. Only 2 percent of New Orleans residents ranked “hurricane protection/rebuilding flood walls, levees” as a top concern.

Don’t miss anything! Sign up to get TMC’s smart analysis in your inbox, three days a week.

Neil Malhotra (@namalhotra) is the Edith M. Cornell professor of political economy at the Stanford Graduate School of Business.