Home > News > Coethnicity
122 views 10 min 0 Comment

Coethnicity

- December 31, 2009

My colleague Macartan Humphreys recently came out with book, Coethnicity (with James Habyarimana, Daniel Posner, and Jeremy Weinstein, addresses the question of why public services and civic cooperation tend to be worse in areas with more ethnic variation. To put it another way: people in homogeneous areas work well together, whereas in areas of ethnic diversity, there’s a lot less cooperation.

From one perspective, this one falls into the “duh” category. Of course, we cooperate with people who are more like us! But it’s not so simple. Macartan and his colleagues discuss and discard a number of reasonable-sounding explanations before getting to their conclusion, which is that people of the same ethnic group are more able to enforce reciprocity and thus are more motivated to cooperate with each other.

But, looking at it another way, I wonder whether it’s actually true that people in homogenous societies cooperate more. I think of the U.S. is pretty ethnically diverse, compared to a lot of much more disorganized places. One question is what counts as ethnicity. Fifty or a hundred years ago in the U.S., I think we’d be talking about Irish, English, Italians, etc., as different ethnic groups, but now they’d pretty much all count as white. To what extent is noncooperation not just the product of ethnic diversity but also a contributor to its continuation?

Macartan and his collaborators address some of these issues in their concluding chapter, and I’m sure there’s a lot more about this in the literature. This is an area of political science that I know almost nothing about. When a researcher such as myself writes a book in American politics, we don’t have to explain much–our readers are already familiar with the key ideas. Comparative politics, though, is a mystery to the general reader such as myself.

I should say something about the methods used by Macartan and his collaborators. They went to a city in Uganda, told people about their study, and performed little psychology/economics experiments on a bunch of volunteers. Each experiment involved some task or choice involving cooperation or the distribution of resources, and they examined the results by comparing people, and pairs of people, by ethnicity, to see where and how people of the same or different ethnic groups worked together in different ways.

One thing that was cool about this study, and which reminded me of research I’ve seen in experimental psychology, was that they did lots of little experiments to tie up loose ends and to address possible loopholes. Just for example, see the discussion on pages 137-139 of how they rule out the possibility that their findings could be explained by collusion among study participants.

I was also thinking about the implications of their findings for U.S. politics. (Macartan has told me that he doesn’t understand how there can be a whole subfield of political scientist specializing in American politics, but he told me that he’ll accept “Americanists” by thinking of us as comparative politics scholars who happen to be extremely limited in what we study.) The authors allude to research by Robert Putnam and others comparing civic behavior in U.S. communities of varying ethnic homogeneity, but I also wonder about public opinion at the national level, not just local cooperation but also to what extent people feel that “we’re all in this together” and to what extent people evaluate policies and candidates based on how they effect their ethnic group (however defined). I’m also interested in the sometimes-vague links between ethnicity and geography, for example the idea that being a Southerner (in the U.S.) or a Northerner (in England) seems like an ethnic identity. Even within a city, different neighborhoods have different identities.

If I haven’t made the point clear enough already, I think the book is fascinating, and it looks like it will open the door to all sorts of interesting new work as well.

P.S. While typing up these notes, I realized that “sanction” is one of those funny words with two nearly completely opposite definitions. According to dictionary.com, the first definition of this verb is “to authorize, approve, or allow.” But “sanction” also is used in the opposite sense, to mean “punish.” Similarly, the noun can either mean “permission” or “penalty.” It can get confusing at times, to read that some behavior is being sanctioned.

P.P.S. In one of the experiments in the book involves two people and a combination lock. Person A is shown how to use the lock (apparently, these are common in the U.S. but not in Uganda), then person B is given the lock and is given ten minutes to open it. Person A is allowed to give instructions but not to touch the lock. I was surprised to read that 40% of the pairs in this experiment did not succeed in opening the lock! I mean, how hard it be to say, “Turn to the right a few times until you reach the number 17, then turn to the left, . . .”? Was it a language barrier, or was person A sometimes not helping at all, or was there something else going on? Not having ever conducted or participated in such an experiment, I don’t know how to think about this at all.

P.P.S. Some minor comments:

p.6, line 2: They write, “this book departs form the typical social science concern with whether, rather than why, one thing causes another” [italics in original]. This reminds me of something I’ve been thinking about recently, which is that, in social settings, everything “causes” everything else. To put it another way, no effects are zero, and apparent near-zeroes can arise from effects that are positive in some cases and negative in others. (To consider an example from educational research, a new teaching method might work for some students but be counterproductive for others.)

p. 6-7: A related point goes here: the authors give several possible explanation for greater cooperation among coethnics, but I’m suspicious because all these stories go in the same direction. A positive effect need not be composed solely of positive components.

p.8: They discuss that one reason for avoiding cooperation is to avoid being a “sucker.” This reminds me of one of my favorite psychology articles, The norm of self-interest, by Dale Miller.

p.15: Robert Axelrod’s work on the prisoner’s dilemma is mentioned here. I’d just like to point out that, as interesting as that work is, I don’t think it actually applies to the example that Axelrod discussed in his book.

p.51: One of my pet peeves is the presentation of tables that you have to turn the book to read. With a bit of care, this and the other such tables could be formatted to fit right-side-up on the page. (In this case, you could start by removing all the initial zeroes (“0.41” becomes “.41”, etc.) I also admit to finding these tables extremely difficult to read, because I have to distinguish between “Baganda,” “Bagisu,” “Bakiga,” “Basoga,” and several other similarly-named groups. Also, how are these groups ordered in the table? The natural ordering would be from largest to smallest in population, but that doesn’t seem to be what they’re doing here. And is “Munyankole” (p.50) the same as “Banyankole” (p.51)?

Overall, I think the graphical presentations of model estimates throughout the book are excellent.